Author's Name: Stefanie Schurer Date: Fri 08 May 2020 |
Stefanie Schurer
Professor Stefanie Schurer
Stefanie Schurer is a Professor of Economics in the School of Economics at the University of Sydney. She also leads the Economics of Human Development research node at the Charles Perkins Centre. She has produced some of the first insights on the stability and determinants of personality (non-cognitive skills-soft skills-life skills-character skills) over the lifecourse. Her current research program focuses on the impact of public policy on human development. She is a chief investigator on several linked administrative data projects in Australia. She uses such big data to study the consequences of Australia's key family, welfare, and medical policies for (Indigenous) children. She is a Visiting Scholar at the University of Chicago, a Research Fellow at the IZA Bonn and a member of the Human Capital and Economic Opportunity (HCEO) network. She is on the editorial board of the Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. The recipient of numerous fellowships and research grants, she obtained a PhD and Masters degree in Economics from the Ruhr Graduate School in Economics (Germany) and the University of York (UK), respectively.
Subject Area Expertise
Microeconomics, Economics of Human Development, Public Policy
Website
Company website: www.stefanie-schurer.com
Responses (19)
Budget 2024
Poll 64
Panelists were asked to comment on two questions:
Is the budget likely to achieve its aim of getting inflation back within the RBA target band by the end of this year and back to 2.75% by mid next year?
And
On May 14, the government delivered a budget designed, in the Treasurer's words, to "focus on fighting inflation in the near term and then growth in the medium term " - What grade would you give the budget, given that objective? A, B, C, D, E or F
Wes Mountain/The Conversation, CC BY-ND https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nd/4.0/
NOT SURE Private demand is forecasted to grow at less than 2% in the financial year ahead and around 3% in the year after, so it is likely inflation will be cut back to under 3%. But predictions are hard. Especially the future.
A
The 2024-25 budget has been designed in a cautious manner, as cost of living support is not paid out in ways to boost demand in the private sector. The energy bill rebate included in the budget will be paid "silently" ? it comes in the form of a rebate so that consumers have lower bills to pay. This makes it different to an unconditional cash payout (such as a stimulus payment during the global financial crisis) that could be used for any purchases. The amount is only $300 per annum (10% of the 2004 Baby Bonus) or $2.6 billion. This total amount is less than half of a percent of what retail trade turnover is in a given year (https://www.abs.gov.au/statistics/industry/retail-and-wholesale-trade/retail-trade-australia/latest-release). The budget was also careful with the Stage 3 tax cuts, targeting them towards lower- and middle-income earners, which is laudable as it is for these groups that will feel the cost of living pressures most. Private demand is forecasted to grow below 2% in the next year and around 3% in the year after, so the economy is not predicted to be overheating. There are many other great measures in the budget, most notably the longer-term investments to facilitate the economy's green transition.
Transition to net zero - ape the US Inflation Reduction Act?
Poll 62
Panellists were asked "Which of the options set out below best describes the kind of approach the Australian government should take to the US Inflation Reduction Act? (Pick 1)"
To support homegrown emerging green technologies | The payoff to clean-energy innovation has increased
Provide more grants to innovative firms across the entire economy
Grants and subsidies are not necessarily the same, even though the terms are often used interchangeably. Subsidies are current payments with the aim of boosting production or changing the price of a good. Grants are direct financial contributions for specific activities that support the policy objectives. Grants and subsidies however should always be considered a short-term measure to induce structural change, until an industry can survive on its own legs (until marginal cost equals price). I personally prefer grants over pure subsidies (such as those that lower costs for producers), as grants can be set up in a competitive process in which companies have to bid for funding. This ensures that the most competitive proposals receive funding. It would be preferable if companies across the entire economy could benefit from short-term government support so that the whole industrial production can change, not just segments of the economy that are linked to specific markets (here US markets). However, as shown in other countries, a serious shift to cleaner energy adoption & production permeating the economy requires more serious measures than subsidies and grants. What is furthermore needed are policy measures that lift the price of dirty energy production and consumption (fossil-fuelled economy). One example is the minimum floor price for carbon that Germany recently introduced. It has been suggested elsewhere that such a minimum floor price could accelerate the adoption of cleaner technologies. Another measure needed is the introduction of a market mechanism that allows companies to trade their rights to carbon emissions. Countries in the EU, which has trialled an emission trading scheme since 2005, have already decoupled their GDP growth from carbon emissions and are thus well prepared to grow with green energy Economies with cleaner energy benefit from a series of social outcomes other than economic growth, innovation, and environmental protection: They have healthier and safer populations. The health benefits of clean energy are comfortably outperforming the perceived costs of changing the structure of the economy. ?Picking winners? was never a good policy in the past, and will not be in the future. This remains true even if other countries do it. Facilitating innovation in general is a good policy.
We can and should keep unemployment below 4%, says our survey of top economists
Poll 60
Australia’s leading economists believe Australia can sustain an unemployment rate as low as 3.75% – much lower than the latest Reserve Bank estimate of 4.25% and the Treasury’s latest estimate of 4.5%.
improving the quality of employment services, relaxing industrial relations regulation to allow for greater "flexibility" (as defined by employers), creating more incentives for business R&D
4.5
This question is about how to increase employment without triggering inflationary pressures to the economy. The single most effective policy measure for this would be to increase fair competition for businesses. By fair I mean that no single business can exploit market power. To become and stay competitive, businesses have to invest in their own R&D (Research and Development), so that they can produce products that are sought after in a global market. Companies that are competitive in a global market generate sustainable (and potentially expanding) employment opportunities for workers. However, to stay competitive, companies sometimes need flexibility in offering a great variety of work contracts, not just a one-size fits all wage contract (eg to buffer against fluctuations in the market). The quality of employment services is critical too, as employment agencies can help workers to find the companies and the jobs that match their skills (so that there is less frictional unemployment in the economy). I would have also opted for "better targeting immigration" (but I could only tick 3 boxes), so that the right skills can be imported if needed. High quality employment services could help flag which skills are most in demand (but cannot be filled) by businesses. Skill shortage can be solved in the medium run by importing the right skills (immigration) and in the longer-run by boosting tertiary education.
Budget 2023
Poll 59
Our panellists were asked the following 2023 budget question: "On May 9, the government delivered a budget designed, in the Treasurer's words, to strike a balance between relief, repair and restraint'. What grade would you give the budget, given that objective: A, B, C, D, E or F?"
Wes Mountain/The Conversation, CC BY-ND - https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nd/4.0/
Overall rating: B - Keeping inflationary pressures in check: C
B
OVERALL COMMENTS: The budget delivers on both relief (cost of living relief for eligible households and small business), and repair/restraint (creating a budget surplus in this financial year of $4 billion). This is not a budget season for elaborate expansions of government spending. I am pleased to see the government produced a surplus of at least $4 billion, but more could have been done (up to $8 billion, see discussion by Steve Hamilton, which I personally support). What is really positive to see is that the fiscal relief measures are targeted at the more vulnerable households. Most notable is the expansion of access to the Parenting Payment (Single) for single parents who are the principal carers, 91% of whom are women. Access to support has been curtailed since the mid-2000 when the Howard government declared an unimaginable war on single mothers. Many may have forgotten this, but in 2006 the Howard government introduced the Welfare to Work policy, which forced single carers to participate more in the labour market. The policy was euphemistically called a self-reliance booster for single carers on income support. It entirely ignored the immense time and financial pressures under which single carers of small dependent children operate. Single carers have to do two jobs: they have to be main income earner and they have to care for and stimulate and nurture their dependent children. Forcing single carers to spend more time in the labour market at a pittance wage, and without affordable and high-quality child care, means that these carers will spend much less time stimulating their children's soft and hard skills. The Welfare to Work policy blatantly ignored the reasons for why single carers are alone (often to avoid domestic violence). We ? Alexandra de Gendre from University of Melbourne, Angela Zhang and I (both University of Sydney) ? have evaluated the changing plight of single mothers over the past two decades of welfare reforms. Single motherhood has important intergenerational consequences through the development of the child, thus financial and moral support is key. We concluded that, in the presence of positive spillover effects, welfare payments to vulnerable families may function as a social investment rather than a sunk cost. Read more here. There are many other positive spending priorities in the budget, among others creating the incentives for doctors to provide bulk-billing services, funding that helps vulnerable and high-need families to access GP services at affordable cost, and incentives for energy upgrades that help households save and to reduce reliance on fossil fuels. What is truly missing, as every year, is a strong and unambiguous commitment to climate change policies. INFLATION COMMENTS: It is a challenging if not impossible task to attribute any causal interpretation on the effect the budget may have on inflationary pressures. The budget can influence both inflation itself and inflation expectations (which will affect inflation in the future). The budget included significant amount of relief payments to poorer households that ? according to theoretical and empirical research findings ?are more likely to spend the extra amounts provided. This is likely to create some inflationary pressures. The budget is relatively careful, as a large amount of windfall income has not been spent but saved to reduce national debt. I keep a neutral stance on whether the budget can relief inflationary pressures, as there is no way to study this question in scientific rigorous way.
How economists would raise $20 billion per year
Poll 58
When panellests were asked to find an extra A$20 billion per year to fund government priorities like building nuclear submarines and responding to climate change, Australia’s top economists overwhelmingly back land tax, increased resource taxes, an attack on negative gearing and extending the scope of the goods and services tax.
Photo credit by Joshua Hoehne on Unsplash
Efficiency picks: Introduce or increase land taxes (possibly with cut in stamp duty) Increase resource taxes Equity picks: Wind back superannuation tax concessions Introduce inheritance taxes Increase the corporate tax rate
Efficiency comments: It is impossible to think about this question with only efficiency gains in mind. Any tax change will change the incentives and therefore behaviour. If only efficiency gains are of interest, none of the options above are therefore particularly useful. Efficiency gains can be achieved by taking away administrative overhead of transfer programs (eg conditional cash transfers, auditing of low income tax payers, scrutiny of NDIS applications). For instance, instead of running a large scale unemployment insurance scheme where eligibility needs to be checked and approved by an administrator, a universal basic income could be granted where everyone is eligible. In principle, one could think of it as a replacement of the welfare state. Some have argued that the saved costs could entirely fund such a program and raising more money than its cost. However, if I was forced to choose any option above, I would recommend taxing land, and resources taken from the land. These are immobile capital and transactions, respectively, that cannot easily be moved to another country to avoid the tax. Thus, change in behaviour is the least likely among the options presented above. Equity comments: If equity concerns played a role as well then it would be obvious to introduce taxes and concessions which the wealthy of Australia benefit from most such as non-existence of inheritance taxes, superannuation tax concessions and tax concessions from negatively geared properties (but not the family home!). What is truly missing from the above list is a carbon tax. Climate change costs will be borne by the next generation. A carbon tax could dramatically change incentives of companies and households today, and raise revenue from intergenerationally unfair economic behaviours. I would also take away all subsidies to the fossil fuel industry. Government documents show that in the 2021-22 budget year, measures that wholly, primarily or partly assist the fossil fuel industry cost federal, state and territory governments $11.6 billion. Hence, if $20 billion needed to be raised, over 50% could be raised simply by taking away subsidies to the fossil fuel industry in Australia. See more information here: https://australiainstitute.org.au/wp-content/uploads/2022/03/P1198-Fossil-fuel-subsidies-2022-WEB.pdf
Is education or immigration the answer to our skills shortage? We asked 50 economists
Poll 56
Investing in Australians’ education is far more important than immigration in resolving the nation’s skills shortages, according to leading economists surveyed in the lead-up to this week’s jobs and skills summit.
The 50 top Australian economists polled by the Economic Society of Australia and The Conversation are recognised by their peers as leaders in their fields, including economic modelling, labour markets and public policy.
Wes Mountain/The Conversation, CC BY-ND
Macroeconomic policy Education and skills Green jobs
Green jobs Australia needs to catch up speedily with its Net Zero emission commitments. Australia is one of the very few countries in the OECD which has not yet achieved a decoupling of CO2 emissions and economic growth. https://www.theguardian.com/business/commentisfree/2021/jun/06/australia-looks-set-to-lose-its-opportunity-to-decouple-gdp-growth-from-carbon-emissions For this reason, it is imperative for the government to generate the incentives that help businesses create green jobs and that help universities and the vocational training system (such as TAFE) to build the skills to match future demand for green job workers. Thus, macroeconomic policy (fiscal policy, trade policy, industry policy) will be an important focus of the Jobs and Skills summit. Fiscal policy has to create such incentives such as subsidising green jobs generation and by penalising companies and financial institutions that invest in fossil fuel industries. Industry policy could focus on providing subsidies to implement feasibility studies for green energy production. One such example is the HySupply Study, a German-Australian feasibility study on Hydrogen generation and export. The project will create 8,000 green jobs. Green hydrogen can be exported worldwide at relatively low cost. https://english.bdi.eu/article/news/hysupply/
'It’s important not to overreact’: Australia’s top economists on how to fix high inflation
Poll 55
Australia’s top economists are divided about how to tackle ballooning inflation of 6.1% that’s forecast to climb to a three-decade high of 7.75% by the end of the year.
Wes Mountain/The Conversation, CC BY-ND
Push for below-inflation wage rises in the Fair Work Commission Super profits tax on fossil fuel producers with revenue used to reduce cost of services Increase income taxes with revenue used to reduce cost of services Raise taxes on higher income earners
2%
It is critical now that the Reserve Bank of Australia raises interest (cash) rates hard and fast (my guess is to about 3.5% by the end of 2022), so that inflation expectations are not accelerated. Consumers need to understand that current inflation is temporary. If rates increase quickly, the Australian dollar will increase in value which will make imports cheaper and will reduce demand for local products. This decrease in external demand will be helpful to reduce inflationary pressures domestically. The government should increase taxation, preferably of individuals in the higher income brackets and companies that invest in fossil fuel production locally or worldwide. This will reduce high demand domestically (and hopefully discourage investments in unsustainable industries, which would be a plus for tackling climate change issues). I sincerely hope that trade unions will refrain from negotiating higher nominal wages, as this would lock in higher inflation expectations. It would make us all poorer. I also recommend that the government invests heavily and swiftly in green energy and electric vehicles so that household consumption is less dependent on highly volatile and currently excessively costly fuel prices. For instance, electric vehicles should not be priced as luxury cars and fossil-fueled cars should not receive subsidies. The cut in the fuel excise tax by the previous government was economically an unsound policy and should be stopped immediately. It sent the wrong signal to consumers. The earlier consumers change to sustainable consumption the better for Australian economic, environmental and social welfare.
Prioritising issues for the incoming Government
Poll 54
Panellists were asked:
"From this list, please pick the three issues you think will be the most important for the incoming government and should be the most important in the election".
Wes Mountain/The Conversation, CC BY-ND
.
Australia has fallen behind dramatically with the richer countries in the world to implement measures to reach its Zero Net Emissions 2050 goals. Ranking "dead last" on climate issues (Climate Council) is not only embarrassing in an international context, but also incredibly shortsighted given Australia's exposure to extreme weather events such as extreme heat days and excessive rain. This should be the single most important issue for the incoming government. Countries like Germany, Norway, Denmark, among many others could provide valuable case studies on how to navigate the treacherous transition period. Of course there are other important issues that should be considered such as long-term investments in education (including tertiary education and vocational training) to produce the human capital needed to change the structure of Australia's industry, which is particularly critical if immigration numbers remain capped.
Australia’s top economists back carbon price, say benefits of net-zero outweigh cost
Poll 50
Ahead of November’s Glasgow climate talks, our panellists were asked
"Australia would likely benefit overall from the national economy transitioning to net-zero emissions by 2050"
Photo credit "Wes Mountain/The Conversation, CC BY-ND"
An economy-wide carbon price (either via a cap-and-trade scheme or an emissions tax)
Agree
The great fear of opponents of carbon-reduction policies is that Australia's economy will suffer permanently. Thus, the key challenge for Australia will be to find ways to decouple energy-related emissions from economic growth. The good news is that many countries worldwide have already achieved this (eg Sweden, Denmark Germany, UK, even the US). Countries that transitioned to cleaner modes of economic activity have used multiple policy tools to induce a shift. I would like to highlight one of them: Emission trading schemes (ETS), one of many tools to price carbon. Coming from the tradition of Rhine capitalism, I consider ETS the most desirable pricing mechanism. Almost 40 countries in the world (including the European Union & UK) and over 20 sub-national jurisdictions have implemented such schemes. Their benefit is that they are the least invasive policy tool and businesses prefer it (over eg carbon taxes) because they give them financially and operationally more flexibility. It is unfortunate that Australia abandoned a long-planned national ETS in 2013 after a change in government. From an economist's perspective, a reintroduction of the ETS would be the single most important "first step" for the Australian government to achieve "net zero by 2050" without compromising economic growth. ETS would create the right institutional framework and incentives for businesses to move away from carbon-intensive industries and reduce the industrial sector share of the economy. But I would like to highlight the importance of other government tools that can be used as second and thirds steps: Subsidies for businesses to invest in renewable energies and investments in low-carbon transport including electric vehicles and urban planning. Thus, "net zero by 2050" is a real opportunity to modernise and innovate. A desirable side effect -- that is rarely discussed in this context - is that many public health concerns (eg respiratory illness) will be mitigated too: cleaner air will cause less respiratory disease in our population-dense cities and fewer extreme heat days will save lives.
Promoting vaccination uptake in Australia
Poll 49
"What measures should Australian governments adopt to promote demand for vaccination once supply is no longer a constraint?"
Photo credit "Wes Mountain/The Conversation, CC BY-ND"
National advertising campaigns;Mandatory vaccination for higher risk occupations;Lotteries with cash or prizes for the vaccinated;Vaccine passports for higher-risk settings (eg. flights, restaurants, major events)
Mandates, passports, more fun and less fear In a world, where individual freedoms are already wildly curbed, vaccination mandates and passports are not an unreasonable or infeasible strategy to boost vaccination rates. This strategy in combination with a variety of softer-touch interventions and fun campaigns to reduce fear will help us re-establish our beloved mobility freedoms. Here are some ideas that also make economic sense. The demand for Covid19 vaccination is a complex matter. Standard economic demand theory breaks down in this context as individuals do not pay a price for the vaccine (although supply is price dependent). Thus, a typical price tool in the government?s tool box to boost demand ? price ceilings ? are of no relevance here. Strategies to increase the quantity of vaccines demanded must therefore involve non-price interventions. I personally consider interventions that shape the expectations, believes and preferences of the yet-to-be vaccinated population as the key starting point. Another important consideration are interventions that reduce transaction costs for people yet-to-be vaccinated. And of course, mandates are critical in a setting where individual decision-making can have major costs to society. Generating 100% vaccination uptake from people who are expected to be affected by the Covid19 outbreak (or any other infectious disease of great public health concern) is impossible. Consider for example the so-called MMR1 vaccination to prevent the spread of highly contagious childhood diseases. Australia has a vaccination coverage for five-year olds of 95% today, a coverage deemed necessary to achieve herd immunity for eg the highly infectious measles. This number wasn't always that high. Australia achieved this coverage through implicit mandates. A requirement for children to meet immunisation schedules has been attached to childcare payments since 1998 and for the FTB-A supplement from 2012. Families can access their family-related Centrelink payments only if their child?s vaccination schedule is up to date. In 2015 exemption rules were tightened to make it harder for so-called ?conscientious objectors?. Some states have also introduced vaccination mandates for children to access child-care centres (eg NSW in 2014). So, federal and state legislation can provide for such targeted mandates. Some may argue that immunisation mandates are too invasive, that they would be restricting individual freedoms too much: the freedom over one?s own body and its integrity. However, in a world where individual freedoms -- local, domestic, and international mobility -- are already radically and continuously restricted, mandates don?t appear to be off the charts. I support mandating vaccination of high-risk workers if relevant medical exemptions are provided for. A recent opinion piece in the Medical Journal of Australia argues that this is legally possible: "The federal government has limited but available powers to enact compulsory vaccination for high-risk workers under the Biosecurity Act, and while there is variation among states and territories, compulsory vaccination is allowed for in Victoria and WA and could be enabled via passage of specific legislation elsewhere" (see https://www.mja.com.au/journal/2021/215/1/medico-legal-considerations-mandatory-covid-19-vaccination-high-risk-workers). Note, the Australian Government announced end of June 2021 that COVID-19 vaccinations would be made mandatory for residential aged care workers. All workers in aged care will be required to receive their first dose of the vaccine by September this year. Some states and territories have also issued public health orders mandating vaccination for certain industries or workers. For example, Queensland has a public health order in place mandating vaccination for health service employees who are likely to encounter and treat people with COVID-19. I personally support such measures during an epidemic, although I would never opt for such policies under normal circumstances. In addition, the Government can and should use more standard tools from the economist's toolbox. As a guiding principle for any intervention, life should be made easier for people who are vaccinated, and more difficult for people who are not. This will create the right incentives for unvaccinated people to reconsider their choices. It is for this reason that I personally support vaccination passports that grant access to large public events (e.g. access to concerts, stadiums, lectures ect) and most importantly domestic and international travel. The European Union has introduced such requirement to re-establish basic individual freedoms (no quarantine is required if a negative Covid test is presented). Some would even go so far to make them compulsory to access restaurants. France is currently battling with such ideas. I am personally less in favour of paying cash incentives to highly-reluctant vaccine uptakers. I am not generally opposed to cash incentives. They have proven useful in other public health campaigns. For instance, financial incentives are effective to reduce the incidence of smoking during pregnancy or to increase the willingness to attend school during adolescence to reach a critical education threshold. The main problem with cash incentives is that they cannot be targeted in the context of Covid19. For instance, if the government considered in the public debate a cash transfer of let?s say 300$, people may wait with vaccination until the Government will start paying the cash incentive. That would delay vaccination rollout. Thus, I am opposed to such cash incentives. I am more in favour of paying incentives to general practitioners to ensure that their registered patients are up to date with Covid vaccination and provide the relevant information. Let them call up their registered patients and lure them into their practice for the jab. It's possibly one of the very few examples where supplier-induced demand is a good thing. Australia has experience with such initiatives. The 2015 budget earmarked $26.4 million over four years to improve immunisation coverage rates, particularly in children and adolescents. The Government intended to make an incentive payment to doctors and other immunisation providers when they identify a child who is overdue for vaccination and call them in for a catch up, fund an awareness campaign to promote immunisation and address parents' concerns regarding immunisation and; expand the existing National Human Papillomavirus Vaccination Program Register to include all adolescent vaccinations delivered in schools under the NIP. So, we have already a lot of experience with such incentives. This brings me to talk about softer-touch interventions. A big-win lottery could be helpful to put a positive vibe and some fun on the whole vaccination rollout. This lottery should be combined with a funky national advertising campaign that communicates simple and clear messages about the effectiveness of vaccines. The government could hire sports and entertainment celebrities to speak out. It could be combined with a fun competition that encourages citizens to provide their own solutions to the vaccine hesitancy problem. The government could offer prizes for the three most innovative and practical ideas to boost vaccination rates. Instead of being numbed by fear, Australians should feel empowered through the vaccine rollout. Here are some ideas how philantropic organisations have incentivised crowdsourcing of ideas to create better neighbourhoods: https://ssir.org/articles/entry/six_ways_contests_improve_philanthropy Last but not least, I propose that the state governments bring vaccination clinics closer to the homes of people. I want to see vaccination trucks (like those blood donation trucks) drive through neighbourhoods. During a pandemic, reasonable people will avoid public places. They will not want to go to their GP practice where they may catch Covid19 or other diseases. As we will continue to be in lockdown for some extended time, vaccination trucks should be driving through neighbourhoods now and knock on people?s doors. My neighbour told me she could get the Astra Zeneca jab any day from her GP, but she is wary of going to the GP and doesn't want to spend the time travelling. Thus, I suggest the Government should help reduce these transaction costs. Mobile vaccination trucks will achieve higher vaccination rates.
Policies to deliver higher wage growth
Poll 48
Our panellists were asked
"Higher wages growth is now a top priority of the RBA in its efforts to sustain stronger economic growth. Please identify the three of these government policies you think would best help deliver higher wages growth".
Photo credit "Wes Mountain/The Conversation, CC BY-ND"
.
Measures to boost productivity growth;Measures to boost business investment;Maintaining high governm
Australia is currently experiencing supply shocks that translate into demand shocks because of renewed lock downs. Current forecasts suggest varying degrees of lock downs will be part of daily life way into 2022. Thus, the Government needs to step in with a generous fiscal policy to compensate for short and longer-term income losses among businesses and households, and unfavorable business investment climates. I personally support hard lock downs only if the Government steps in to compensate for such income losses. Given longer term trends in productivity and demographic change (with a declining population), we need more migration (both temporary and permanent), not less. Our own research - with Maryam Nagsh Nejad (UTS) - has shown that Australia's migrants have brought a high level of skills - both cognitive and non-cognitive - to Australia, skills that have also been passed on to the children of migrants. High levels of skills are needed for generating productivity growth. Links to this research can be found on my homepage: https://www.stefanie-schurer.com/publications
Transition to electric cars
Poll 47
This month, our panellists were asked whether Australia should take action to speed the transition to electric cars.
"As part of efforts to reduce carbon emissions, Australian governments should take action to accelerate the take up, or take no action to accelerate the take up of electric cars"
Photo credit "Wes Mountain/The Conversation, CC BY-ND"
Remove the luxury car tax from all-electric cars, Subsidise the purchase of all all-electric cars, Subsidise public charging points for electric cars
10
Subsidies are an effective tool to change consumer preferences, including tastes for cars. In the past decade, the market share of Sport Utility Vehicles (SUVs) climbed to almost 50% (https://www.carsguide.com.au/car-advice/australian-car-market-car-sales-statistics-and-figures-70982). The biggest winners in recent years were dual-cab utes. These are super-bulky tanks that take up almost two lanes in family neighbourhoods. They easily knock cyclists off the road because their owners don't know how wide they are. The reason for the stark increase in their sales is that the government gives tax benefits (when used for work) and special parking privileges in cities (ute drivers can use loading zones: https://www.carsguide.com.au/car-news/toyota-hilux-not-tesla-model-3-why-the-government-incentivises-us-to-buy-utes-instead-of). There are no tax or other incentives for electric vehicles (EVs) except for a modest lift in tax thresholds that comes into effect 1 July 2021 (https://thedriven.io/2021/06/01/australia-raises-luxury-car-tax-threshold-for-evs-for-second-year-in-row/). It comes at no surprise that such EVs are rarely seen on Australian roads. Sales statistics confirm this impression. Australia is falling behind dramatically in a global competition for carbon emission reduction. The smartest governments worldwide now compete for being the quickest to transform their countries into low-carbon economies, clean technology powerhouses, and locations of pollution-free cities. Whereas the most innovative countries in the world heavily subsidise EV sales and privilege EV users in cities and on the roads (e.g. Norway, Germany), Australia opts for subsidising the big polluters. And why? Australia builds its economic recovery on ute sales and thus gives those tax write offs (https://thenewdaily.com.au/finance/2021/06/11/utes-tax-write-offs/). It's for a short-term gain. And that is idiotic.
The Federal Budget May 2021
Poll 46
"On May 11, the government delivered a budget designed, in the Treasurer's words, to 'secure Australia's economic recovery and build for the future'. What grade would you give the budget given that objective, A, B, C, D, E, F?"
Photo credit Wes Mountain/The Conversation, CC BY-ND
.
D
Under the assumption that "A" implies the best grade and "F" the worst - I assign the budget a grade of "D" if the aim was to ?secure Australia?s economic recovery and build for the future?. The budget does not include critical expenditure items that demonstrate investment in the future. I welcome the strong "welfare" elements of the budget, by supporting low- and middle-income earners, single moms, and families with children through the tax system. Resource allocations to the aged-care sector, mental health care, and child care are likely to be highly beneficial for social welfare. However, I am missing visionary long-term investments. I had hoped for a "New Deal" type of budget. Rather than just handing out subsidies to specific groups of society and keeping workers employed, I would have liked to see the Government commit to long-term investments in sectors that will generate jobs 10-30 years down the track, such as clean energy production, pharmaceutical research & vaccine production, communication technologies, and building research infrastructure & skills. It is surprising to see that no investments are made into universities at a time where the tertiary education sector is hardest hit through border lockdown and at risk of loosing its competitive edge. Given that Australia has been falling behind dramatically in its vaccination effort and ability to secure vaccination doses, I would have expected the Government to invest heavily in pharmaceutical research and vaccine manufacturing. The 2021 budget is built on the assumption that the Government's vaccination rollout will be complete by the end of 2021. At current rollout rates per week, it will take Australia's 30 more months to fully vaccinate its population. It is now time to open up vaccination to everyone who wants to. Because of low take up among those eligible, the Government is risking to waste many doses which expire within the next three months.
Does the budget rebuild our economy and create jobs?
Poll 43
"On 6 October, the Government delivered a budget designed, in the Treasurer's words, to 'rebuild our economy and create jobs'. What grade would you give the budget given the objective? A, B, C, D, E, F"
Photo Credit: Wes Mountain/The Conversation, CC BY-ND
C
I would have liked to see more nation-building investment projects and more support for women, in particular working moms, who bore the brunt of the lockdown and other consequences of the pandemic.
Top economists want JobSeeker boosted by $100+ per week and tied to wages
Poll 44
"Ahead of a decision about any permanent increase expected early next year, The Conversation and the Economic Society of Australia asked 45 of Australia’s leading economists where they thought JobSeeker should settle."
Remain indexed in line with the CPI
Unemployment benefits should be a short-term measure to support individuals who experienced voluntary or involuntary unemployment. The payment should be considered as a temporary measure. Thus, no incentives should be created to get habituated to the payment. Pensions are different, because retirement is a permanent state. The needs of the elderly are potentially higher (e.g. due to higher health care expenditures and care support), which justifies as more generous indexing. Yet, the original Newstart rate of $287.50 appears too low for e.g. single mothers. I have argued elsewhere that Newstart should be increased by about a sixth to factor in higher consumption needs of vulnerable families.
October Budget 2020 - preferred four programs
Poll 42
"The October budget will see the government announce additional policies to support recovery. Please nominate the four programs you think would be the most effective (for an intervention of a given size) over the next two years"
Photo Credit: Wes Mountain/The Conversation, CC BY-ND
Infrastructure projects, Incentives for renewable energy, Incentives for cleaner fossil fuel energy, More funding for education and training
Australia would fare well if it adopted a New Deal type of investment strategy in its next budget to buffer the economic crisis and increase employment opportunities. Crisis spending should be used to invest in human capital development (education & training), large, socially-valuable infrastructure projects and in future-oriented industries. All of these investments will generate high returns in the future, while picking up the unemployed from the streets. Wage subsidies or cash transfers are very good short-term measures but they should not be used in the medium to longer term. They create disincentives for firms to be competitive and use resources in the most efficient way. In plain terms, they make business owners lazy. Incentivising investment in renewable/clean energy today will create jobs and ensure that Australian technology becomes competitive in this worldwide growing market. It will also ensure that Australia remains an attractive and clean place to live. Think of Norway, which generates all of its energy needed with hydropower. Excess energy is exported to other countries. Country is clean and livable. Large infrastructure investments can help to generate immediate employment, while creating a great public resource that pays dividends in the future. A very good example is the Hoover Dam, which was built during the Great Depression. It generated employment for over 20000 men during its 5-year construction. Why not building a massive dam in Australia like the Hoover Dam? Why not building a new Sydney Symphony Orchestra Building (like the "Berlin Philharmony"). Why not expanding the National Parks? Why not building Green Libraries all over Australia? Why not extending the National Broadband Network further, so that Telemedicine becomes feasible and successful? Why not building an Aboriginal History Museum dedicated to Aboriginal and Torres Straight Islander culture, art and economy? I thus support budget items that finance public investments that pay off in the future, and generate employment today.
Government Debt during the COVID19 Crisis
Poll 40
"Governments should provide ongoing fiscal support to boost aggregate demand during the economic crisis and recovery, even if it means a substantial increase in public debt"
Photo Credit: Wes Mountain/The Conversation, CC BY-ND
Strongly agree
9
Australia has one of the lowest government debts -- as percentage of GDP -- among OECD countries. In December 2019, this debt ratio was 45%. In comparison to Germany (60%), the UK (81%), EU (80%) and the US (107%), Australia's government debt ratio is low. It is similar to Switzerland's and Norway's (~41%), two exceptionally rich countries with a healthy and functional public sector and a thriving private sector. Thus, Australia will be able to increase its public debt substantially, without compromising its financial health.
Wage freeze for economic recovery
Poll 39
"A freeze in the minimum wage will support Australia's economic recovery"
Photo credit: Wes Mountain/The Conversation, CC BY-ND
Strongly disagree
9
I have understood the question as hypothetical, because the Fair Work Commission (FWC) has just increased national minimum wages by 3 percent, amounting to an extra $21.60 a week. This is a lower increase than the increases seen in the past two years and what the Australian Council of Trade Unions had requested (6 percent). Yet, the increase is substantially higher than what industry groups had hoped for (1.8-2 percent) and expected inflation for 2020-21 (experts predict 1.2-1.6 percent). From an economic perspective, the "increase" in the minimum wage, as opposed to a "freeze", is welcomed. My disagreement with the above statement and my support for an increase in the minimum wage is based on the following argument: Theoretically, minimum wages have ambiguous effects on aggregate demand. On the one hand, they could increase aggregate demand, as lower-income workers tend to have higher marginal propensities to consume. On the other hand, they may reduce employment and thus aggregate demand. As there is little empirical evidence for the latter proposition in the international and national literature and because of modest inflation expectations, I would have rejected the idea of freezing the minimum wage. Australia’s minimum wage is unlike the ones in the UK and US. Minimum wages exist in many industries and have a wide range, affecting almost 40% of Australian workers directly and indirectly. A large proportion of Australian workers - around 1 in 6 - will be directly affected by the minimum wage increases offered by the FWC, many of which are low-income earners. To support Australia’s economic recovery, it is critical to keep consumer spending high in general, but specifically of low-income earners who are more likely to spend their income gains. This could compensate for aggregate demand reductions associated with closed borders and a collapse of international tourism.
Social Distancing Measures, May 2020
Poll 38
"The benefits to Australian society of maintaining social distancing measures sufficient to keep R<1 for COVID-19 are likely to exceed the costs"
Strongly agree
9
In German we say: better a painful ending than an endless pain. Let me explain this. Short and medium term failure to eliminate, or at least slow down the spread of, the coronavirus virus will entail significant political, economic and social costs in the long run. Social distancing measures are no unjustified nuisance. Currently, they are the only option available to policy makers to curtail the capacity of the virus to spread ? measured by R, the so-called reproduction factor. The lower R, the lower is the spread of the virus. Some have argued that we should have gone for herd immunity to deal with the crisis. To achieve herd immunity, a certain share of the population must be infected and we need to assume that exposure to the coronavirus means protection against future infections. R determines how big that share must be. For instance, in a society under normal conditions, Covid's R ~ 2.5. This means that one person infected would spread it to 2.5 others. It has been widely discussed that about 60% of the population would need to be both infected and become immune to the virus (share=1-1/R). Would we like to expose 60% of the population to the virus, knowing that there is no treatment other than ventilation and that about 1% - although a contestable number - are likely to die? I do not think that policy makers would find volunteers for this experiment. Maybe it is better to make the virus behave a bit more like the flu, slow the speed of its spread to R~1.3. In this case, we would still need about 23% of the population to be exposed to achieve herd immunity. With the assumed case mortality rate, that would still imply a loss of life of 57,500 Australians (#deaths=1% of the 23% of population, ~25 million, who were exposed). If that number is still not acceptable, or if we cannot ensure that exposure means protection, which we cannot, then the only other option is virus elimination. This could be achieved, if R<1, or in plain words: every corona-infected person passes the virus on to less than one other person. Germany, which used very strict lockdown measures, achieved this for some time. When R was steadily < 1, and when a role-model testing and tracking system was in place, the Merkel government prepared for opening up the economy. Recent reports have shown that R has increased already to above 1 with the opening of the economy. The world has its eyes on Germany to learn how effective its strategy is to eliminate the virus. So, why do I think that keeping R<1, with the help of social distancing measures, outweighs the likely costs? To answer this question, one needs to think about both short-term and the long-term costs, and the dynamics in the lifecycle of a virus. The short-term costs are predictable. Australia will experience its first recession in almost three decades. Unemployment will rise, businesses will go bankrupt. Whether such recession will cause more deaths than Covid-19, cannot be answered yet. The good news is that the overall evidence from international data, and work that we have produced for Australia, suggests that recessions, if anything reduce mortality. The other good news is that Australia can buffer the economic consequences of the temporary hibernation of its economy through expansive fiscal policy. Expectations of a recession and the practical consequences of the lockdown will also entail psychic costs. They will certainly strain the emotional health of individuals and families, in particular the most vulnerable segments of the population: the old because of loneliness, and the children because of exposure to stressed family environments, a breeding ground for violence and maltreatment. These psychic costs must be taken very seriously by policymakers. Increased resource allocations to mental health and family service providers will be critical, so that they can increase their support services and target where advisable. A policy alternative that avoids, instead of alleviates, such economic and psychic short-term costs, is not advisable. The alternative would have been to have no social distancing measures at all, or to relax those in place prematurely. By prematurely, I mean before R is below 1 for extended periods of time (which scientists say is now happening in Australia). If social distancing measures were relaxed when R were 1 or greater, it would have the consequence that new hot spots of infections and deaths will emerge months down the track. It could even be that the virus comes back in full force, with reproduction rates way above 2. This would force politicians to reintroduce even harsher social distancing measures than the ones we have experienced in the past ten weeks. Such measures would certainly extinguish any revived economic activity. Theoretically, this could happen several times into the future, stretching out the battle against Covid-19 over years. Like a yoyo, the economy would bounce up and down between lockdown and easing, forcing companies, employers, employees, families, carers, and essential service providers to adapt over and over again. The uncertainty would be an emotionally draining and financially expensive exercise. In modern democracies, it is excruciatingly painful for politicians to restrict citizens? basic human rights. It is unlikely to see such rights restricted on a recurring basis without serious social unrest. Although Australia is a rich country, the economy cannot afford to roll out job and business rescue programs, the current one valued at 16% of GDP, whenever a new infection hotspot requires yet another hibernation of the economy. Thus, we must eliminate the virus now. A painful ending, achievable through keeping R<1, is economically and socially less costly, than the endless pain of allowing R to float freely above 1.